h1是什么意思| 11月18日什么星座| paris什么意思| 梦到头发长长了是什么意思| 格力空调睡眠模式1234什么意思| 苦荞茶适合什么人喝| 浮生若梦什么意思| 溥仪和慈禧什么关系| 什么银行卡最好用| 扒皮鱼是什么鱼| 转氨酶高有什么症状| 什么就像什么造句| dn是什么| 1940年属什么生肖| 梦见猪是什么意思| 股癣是什么样的| 原配是什么意思| 阳痿早泄吃什么药好| 吃饱就犯困是什么原因| 染色体是由什么组成的| 手爆皮是什么原因| 白醋泡脚有什么好处| 玉谷叶是什么植物| 怀孕甲减对孩子有什么影响| 息肌丸是什么| 司空见惯是什么意思| 乳房有溢液是什么原因| 鼻咽癌有什么症状| 代茶饮是什么意思| 什么树最值钱| 老人嗜睡是什么原因| 玻璃心什么意思| 4.20是什么星座| 秉承是什么意思| 失落感是什么意思| 拉肚子想吐是什么原因| 6月24号什么星座| 再生纤维素纤维是什么面料| 1994年五行属什么| 过敏性鼻炎喷什么药| 陈小春什么星座| otc药是什么意思| 尼古丁是什么东西| 字形是什么意思| 什么叫粳米| 肠胃不好吃什么水果| 早搏心律不齐吃什么药| 大葱和小葱有什么区别| 珠五行属什么| 壮阳吃什么补最快最好| 氩弧焊对身体有什么危害| 手背肿胀是什么原因| vcr是什么| 猥琐是什么意思| 闯空门什么意思| 印度是什么制度的国家| 小葱拌豆腐的下一句是什么| 哮喘是什么病| 不规则抗体筛查是什么意思| 脊椎炎什么症状| 没有高中毕业证有什么影响| 辩证什么意思| 怀孕前壁和后壁有什么区别| 网球肘用什么药最有效| 容易手麻脚麻是什么原因| 肺不好吃什么| 腰椎退行性改变是什么意思| 短发适合什么脸型| 奡是什么意思| 孕妇心情不好对胎儿有什么影响| 凉粉是什么材料做的| 令加瓦读什么| 什么十分什么| 神经外科治疗什么病| 格局什么意思| 相知相惜是什么意思| 人流需要准备什么东西| 热火朝天是什么意思| 支气管炎吃什么药好| 爱心是什么意思| 结膜炎角膜炎用什么眼药水| 玮五行属什么| 平仓什么意思| 红色加蓝色等于什么颜色| 糖代谢增高是什么意思| 89年属蛇是什么命| 肚脐中间疼是什么原因| 汉族是什么人种| 甘油三酯偏高是什么原因| 黑马什么意思| 儿童超敏c反应蛋白高说明什么| 霍乱是什么| 鸡胸是什么原因引起的| 粉墙用什么| 凤凰代表什么生肖| 1957年属什么生肖| 四大皆空是什么生肖| 感冒低烧是什么原因| 内膜厚是什么原因引起的| 女的排卵期一般是什么时间| 胃不舒服吃什么食物好| 血塞通治什么病| 什么情况下做试管婴儿| 张学良为什么被囚禁| h1是什么意思| 蚊子喜欢什么颜色| 黄芪什么人不能吃| 色盲的世界是什么颜色| 谜底是什么意思| 老鹰茶是什么茶| 脑梗输什么液效果最好| 双源ct主要检查什么| 冬瓜什么季节吃最好| 闺蜜生日送什么礼物好| 喂母乳不能吃什么| 梦见把头发剪短了是什么意思| 山竹为什么叫山竹| 马后炮是什么意思| 穷的生肖指什么生肖| 肚脐左下方疼是什么原因| 浙江有什么旅游景点| 斯里兰卡属于什么国家| 一厢情愿什么意思| 昕五行属什么| 中学为体西学为用是什么意思| 什么是认知障碍| 左眼皮一直跳什么预兆| 处女座跟什么星座最配| 袁崇焕为什么被杀| 遭罪什么意思| 比目鱼又叫什么鱼| 口腔溃疡缺少什么维生素| 印度人为什么叫阿三| 欧阳修是什么居士| 一什么颜色| 01什么意思| 灵魂伴侣是指什么意思| 牛大力是什么| 鼠的三合生肖是什么| 脚腕酸是什么原因| 尿酸高吃什么降的快| 鸿运当头是什么意思| 焦虑吃什么药| 长方形纸可以折什么| iwc手表是什么档次| 献血后吃什么| 美团和美团外卖有什么区别| 乐得什么填词语| 黄磊为什么不娶刘若英| 嘉字属于五行属什么| 饱的偏旁叫什么| 次长是什么职位| 维生素b2有什么作用| 阿莫西林治疗什么| 为什么不可以| 角逐是什么意思| 龋齿是什么原因造成的| 猫咪黑下巴是什么原因| 肚脐周围痛挂什么科| 得意忘形是什么意思| 刮宫是什么意思| 银河系的中心是什么| 什么叫高危行为| 雨花斋靠什么盈利| 6月19号是什么星座| 梦到小男孩是什么意思| 告别是什么意思| 五步蛇又叫什么蛇| 家慈是对什么人的称呼| 关节炎有什么症状| 相对湿度是什么意思| 眼睛不好吃什么补眼睛| hpv跟tct有什么区别| 盆底脱垂有什么症状| 负罪感是什么意思| 国家副主席是什么级别| 心肌供血不足用什么药| 司是什么级别| 西瓜又什么又什么| 肾的作用和功能是什么| 为什么肝区隐隐作痛| 什么的饭菜| 手为什么会掉皮| 杳什么意思| 肾阳虚吃什么中成药| 儿童矮小挂什么科| 1是什么数| ect是什么| 乳腺囊实性结节是什么意思| 水痘不能吃什么食物| 膝盖痛吃什么药好| 为什么不建议小孩吃罗红霉素| 鼻涕倒流吃什么药| 海螺吃什么| 做梦梦见死去的亲人是什么意思| 毛手毛脚什么意思| 川字纹有什么影响| 什么是调和油| 受凉咳嗽吃什么药| 1982属什么生肖| 后脑勺发麻是什么原因| 竹荪是什么| 点子是什么意思| 瑕疵什么意思| 做梦梦到老公出轨代表什么预兆| 下肢静脉曲张是什么原因引起的| 被隐翅虫咬了涂什么药| 人为什么会死亡| 病毒五项检查的是什么| 西洋参有什么用| 虬角为什么要染成绿色| 早上九点半是什么时辰| 肝内小囊肿是什么意思| 银行支行行长什么级别| 膀胱充盈欠佳是什么意思| 慈禧属什么生肖| 失信人是什么意思| 紫色和蓝色混合是什么颜色| 开水烫伤用什么药膏好得快| 串串房是什么意思| 额头上长痘痘什么原因| 口腔溃疡是什么| 蜈蚣泡酒有什么功效| 成何体统是什么意思| 胃烧灼感是什么原因| 心有戚戚焉什么意思| 高血压吃什么降的快| 眼睛干痒滴什么眼药水| 顺铂是什么药| 葡萄糖属于什么糖| 痨病是什么病| 红斑狼疮有什么症状| 棒子面是什么| 茅根是什么| 乙肝235阳性是什么意思| 氯雷他定片治什么病| 羊水指数是什么意思| 早饱是什么意思| 雌二醇凝胶有什么作用| 开普拉多的都是什么人| 寂寞的反义词是什么| 水清则无鱼什么意思| 天天睡觉做梦是什么原因| 小便短赤吃什么药| 柠檬蜂蜜水有什么功效| 青光眼是什么症状| 迈巴赫是什么车| 肿瘤病人不能吃什么| 终年是什么意思| 补刀什么意思| 猫的胡须有什么用处| 额头上长痘是什么原因| 1964年是什么年| 大公鸡衣服是什么牌子| 儿童鼻窦炎吃什么药| 眼睛白色部分叫什么| 香蕉什么时候吃最好| 宝宝睡觉突然大哭是什么原因| 砚是什么东西| 阅读是什么意思| 滴虫病女性有什么症状| 伤疤好了变黑了是什么原因| 蜗牛吃什么食物| 活动性胃炎是什么意思| 百度Jump to content

点燃你肾上腺素的《速度与激情 8》里喝了什么酒

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
百度 “办理组合贷需要先到公积金中心办理审批,再到银行办理审批,整个手续比商贷的时间多出好几倍。

Liberal institutionalism (or institutional liberalism or neoliberalism) is a theory of international relations that holds that international cooperation between states is feasible and sustainable, and that such cooperation can reduce conflict and competition. Neoliberalism is a revised version of liberalism. Alongside neorealism, liberal institutionalism is one of the two most influential contemporary approaches to international relations.[1]

In contrast to neorealist scholarship (which is skeptical of prospects for sustainable cooperation), liberal institutionalism argues that cooperation is feasible and sustainable. Liberal institutionalists highlight the role of international institutions and regimes in facilitating cooperation between states.[2] Robert Keohane's 1984 book After Hegemony used insights from the new institutional economics to argue that the international system could remain stable in the absence of a hegemon, thus rebutting hegemonic stability theory.[3]

Keohane showed that international cooperation could be sustained through repeated interactions, transparency, and monitoring.[4][5] According to Keohane and other liberal institutionalists, institutions facilitate cooperation by:

  • Reducing transaction costs[4][6]
  • Providing information[4][6]
  • Making commitments more credible[4]
  • Establishing focal points for coordination[4][6]
  • Facilitating the principle of reciprocity[4]
  • Extending the shadow of the future[4][7][8]
  • Enabling interlinkages of issues, which raises the cost of noncompliance[9]

Terminology

[edit]

Some call the school of thought rational functionalism instead of liberal institutionalism. Liberal institutionalism is also close to—but not synonymous with—regime theory and neoliberalism.[10][11] Robert Keohane, a political scientist largely responsible for the development of liberal institutionalism, considers his ideas part of institutionalism or rational institutionalism, even though those schools disagree with him on certain points.[12] Keohane dislikes using the adjectives "liberal" or "neoliberal" to describe his work because he also draws from realism, a school of thought that is often contrasted with liberalism.[13][14] Other major influences are the hegemonic stability theory of Stephen Krasner and the work of Charles P. Kindleberger, among others.

Liberal institutionalism differs from other common international relations theories like realism in the fact that it does not ignore internal politics. Furthermore, institutional liberalism follows the idea that democracy and capitalism create systems which not only maintain peace but also create beneficial economic opportunities for those involved. Liberal institutionalists believe that democracies naturally lead to peace because the many govern and not the few, and therefore those who decide to go to war will be the many that serve. This is in stark contrast to monarchies and dictatorships that are more warlike due to the fact that the few that do not serve will go to war. Beyond that liberal institutionalists defend capitalism on an international scale because they believe that if two nations are friendly, democratic, and capitalist the two nations will inevitably negotiate mutually beneficial trade deals.

Role of institutions

[edit]

According to liberal institutionalists, institutions facilitate cooperation by:

  • Reducing transaction costs[4][6]
  • Providing information[4][6]
  • Making commitments more credible[4]
  • Establishing focal points for coordination[4][6]
  • Facilitating the principle of reciprocity[4]
  • Extending the shadow of the future[4][7][8]
  • Enabling interlinkages of issues, which raises the cost of noncompliance[9]

Critics of liberal institutionalism argue that institutions do not overcome power politics; rather, institutions reflect power politics.[15][16] Realist Joseph Grieco argues that liberal institutionalist analyses omit that states pursue relative gains (rather than absolute gains), and that institutionalist analyses that focus on the issue of "cheating" ignore that the relative gains problem is key to why realists believe international cooperation fails.[16] Critics also argue that it is unclear whether institutions have an independent effect on cooperation or whether they reflect that the members are already willing to cooperate and comply.[17] Other critics argue that liberal institutionalist underestimate the enforcement powers of institutions: institutions are often designed to be weak to attract more members,[18] and they tend to be particularly weak on issues related to security rather than economy.[19]

Using logics from historical institutionalism, John Ikenberry argues that institutions may be highly durable because

  • They strengthen expectations about future behavior
  • They build coalitions, routines and connections between actors, which creates incentives for continuity
  • They lead to spillovers, as other forms of cooperation builds around the existing institutions
  • High start-up costs prevent actors from setting up challenger institutions
  • Learning effects create incentives for actors to stick with existing institutions.[20]

Contentions

[edit]

Keohane and Nye

[edit]

Robert O. Keohane and Joseph S. Nye, in response to neorealism, develop an opposing theory they dub "Complex interdependence." Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye explain, "... complex interdependence sometimes comes closer to reality than does realism."[21] In explaining this, Keohane and Nye cover the three assumptions in realist thought: First, states are coherent units and are the dominant actors in international relations; second, force is a usable and effective instrument of policy; and finally, the assumption that there is a hierarchy in international politics.[22]

The heart of Keohane and Nye's argument is that in international politics there are, in fact, multiple channels that connect societies exceeding the conventional Westphalian system of states. This manifests itself in many forms ranging from informal governmental ties to multinational corporations and organizations. Here they define their terminology; interstate relations are those channels assumed by realists; transgovernmental relations occur when one relaxes the realist assumption that states act coherently as units; transnational applies when one removes the assumption that states are the only units. It is through these channels that political exchange occurs, not through the limited interstate channel as championed by realists.

Secondly, Keohane and Nye argue that there is not, in fact, a hierarchy among issues, meaning that not only is the martial arm of foreign policy not the supreme tool by which to carry out a state's agenda, but that there is a multitude of different agendas that come to the forefront. The line between domestic and foreign policy becomes blurred in this case, as realistically there is no clear agenda in interstate relations.

Finally, the use of military force is not exercised when complex interdependence prevails. The idea is developed that between countries in which a complex interdependence exists, the role of the military in resolving disputes is negated. However, Keohane and Nye go on to state that the role of the military is in fact important in that "alliance's political and military relations with a rival bloc."

Lebow

[edit]

Richard Ned Lebow states that the failure of neorealism lies in its "institutionalist" ontology, whereas the neorealist thinker Kenneth Waltz states, "the creators [of the system] become the creatures of the market that their activity gave rise to." This critical failure, according to Lebow, is due to the realists' inability "to escape from the predicament of anarchy." Or rather, the assumption that states do not adapt and will respond similarly to similar constraints and opportunities.[23]

Mearsheimer

[edit]

Norman Angell, a classical London School of Economics liberal, had held: "We cannot ensure the stability of the present system by the political or military preponderance of our nation or alliance by imposing its will on a rival."[24]

Keohane and Lisa L. Martin expound upon these ideas in the mid 1990s as a response to John J. Mearsheimer's "The False Promise of International Institutions", where Mearsheimer purports that, "institutions cannot get states to stop behaving as short-term power maximizers."[25] In fact Mearsheimer's article is a direct response to the liberal-institutionalist movement created in response to neo-realism. The central point in Keohane and Martin's idea is that neo-realism insists that, "institutions have only marginal effects ... [which] leaves [neo-realism] without a plausible account of the investments that states have made in such international institutions as the EU, NATO, GATT, and regional trading organizations."[26] This idea is in keeping with the notion of complex interdependence. Moreover, Keohane and Martin argue that the fact that international institutions are created in response to state interests, that the real empirical question is "knowing how to distinguish the effects of underlying conditions from those of the institutions themselves."[25] The debate between the institutionalists and Mearsheimer is about whether institutions have an independent effect on state behavior, or whether they reflect great power interests that said powers employ to advance their respective interests.[27]

Mearsheimer is concerned with 'inner-directed' institutions, which he states, "seek to cause peace by influencing the behavior of the member states." In doing so he dismisses Keohane and Martin's NATO argument in favor of the example of the European Community and the International Energy Agency. According to Mearsheimer, NATO is an alliance that is interested in "an outside state, or coalition of states, which the alliance aims to deter, coerce, or defeat in war." Mearsheimer reasons that since NATO is an alliance it has special concerns. He concedes this point to Keohane and Martin.[28] However, Mearsheimer reasons, "to the extent that alliances cause peace, they do so by deterrence, which is straightforward realist behavior."[29] In essence, Mearsheimer believes that Keohane and Martin "are shifting the terms of the debate, and making realist claims under the guise of institutionalism.[29]

Mearsheimer criticizes Martin's argument that the European Community (EC) enhances the prospects of cooperation, particularly in the case of Great Britain's sanctioning of Argentina during the Falklands War, where it was able to secure the cooperation of other European states by linking the issues at hand to the EC. Mearsheimer purports that the United States was not a member of the EC and yet the US and Britain managed to cooperate on sanctions, creating an ad hoc alliance which effected change. "... Issue linkage was a commonplace practice in world politics well before institutions came on the scene; moreover, Britain and other European states could have used other diplomatic tactics to solve the problem. After all, Britain and America managed to cooperate on sanctions even though the United States was not a member of the EC."[30]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Powell, Robert (1994). "Anarchy in International Relations Theory: The Neorealist-Neoliberal Debate". International Organization. 48 (2): 313. doi:10.1017/s0020818300028204. S2CID 45773252. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  2. ^ Axelrod, Robert; Keohane, Robert O. (1985). "Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions". World Politics. 38 (1): 226–254. doi:10.2307/2010357. ISSN 1086-3338. JSTOR 2010357. S2CID 37411035. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  3. ^ Keohane, Robert O. (2020). "Understanding Multilateral Institutions in Easy and Hard Times". Annual Review of Political Science. 23 (1): 1–18. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-050918-042625. ISSN 1094-2939.
  4. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m Keohane, Robert O.; Martin, Lisa L. (1995). "The Promise of Institutionalist Theory". International Security. 20 (1): 39–51. doi:10.2307/2539214. ISSN 0162-2889. JSTOR 2539214. S2CID 29960902. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  5. ^ Norrlof, Carla (2010). America's Global Advantage: US Hegemony and International Cooperation. Cambridge University Press. pp. 30–31. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511676406. ISBN 978-0-521-76543-5. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  6. ^ a b c d e f Keohane, Robert O.; Victor, David G. (2011). "The Regime Complex for Climate Change". Perspectives on Politics. 9 (1): 7–23. doi:10.1017/S1537592710004068. ISSN 1541-0986. S2CID 14782206. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  7. ^ a b Oye, Kenneth A. (1985). "Explaining Cooperation Under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies". World Politics. 38 (1): 1–24. doi:10.2307/2010349. ISSN 1086-3338. JSTOR 2010349. S2CID 155047634. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  8. ^ a b Fearon, James D. (1998). "Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation". International Organization. 52 (2): 269–305. doi:10.1162/002081898753162820. ISSN 1531-5088.
  9. ^ a b Poast, Paul (2012). "Does Issue Linkage Work? Evidence from European Alliance Negotiations, 1860 to 1945". International Organization. 66 (2): 277–310. doi:10.1017/S0020818312000069. ISSN 1531-5088. S2CID 154458766. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  10. ^ David Baldwin (1993) Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate. New York: Columbia University Press, p. 10.
  11. ^ Beth A. Simmons and Lisa L. Martin (2002) International Organizations and Institutions. In "Handbook of International Relations", edited by Walter Carlsnaes, Thomas Risse, and Beth A. Simmons, 192–211. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications, p. 195.
  12. ^ Robert Keohane (1993). Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War. In "Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate", edited by David A. Baldwin, 269–300. New York: Columbia University Press, p. 273.
  13. ^ Robert Keohane (1984). After Hegemony: Power and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, p. 14.
  14. ^ Robert Keohane (1993). Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War. In "Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate", edited by David A. Baldwin, 269–300. New York: Columbia University Press, p. 272.
  15. ^ Mearsheimer, John J. (1994). "The False Promise of International Institutions". International Security. 19 (3): 5–49. doi:10.2307/2539078. ISSN 0162-2889. JSTOR 2539078. S2CID 153472054. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  16. ^ a b Grieco, Joseph M. (1988). "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism". International Organization. 42 (3): 485–507. doi:10.1017/S0020818300027715. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 2706787. S2CID 148193812. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  17. ^ Von Stein, Jana (2005). "Do Treaties Constrain or Screen? Selection Bias and Treaty Compliance". The American Political Science Review. 99 (4): 611–622. doi:10.1017/S0003055405051919. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 30038968. S2CID 40607090. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  18. ^ Downs, George W.; Rocke, David M.; Barsoom, Peter N. (1996). "Is the Good News about Compliance Good News about Cooperation?". International Organization. 50 (3): 379–406. doi:10.1017/S0020818300033427. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 2704030. S2CID 154439990. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  19. ^ Lipson, Charles (1984). "International Cooperation in Economic and Security Affairs". World Politics. 37 (1): 1–23. doi:10.2307/2010304. ISSN 1086-3338. JSTOR 2010304. S2CID 154860842. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  20. ^ Ikenberry, G. John (2001). After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order After Major Wars. Princeton University Press. pp. 23, 29–31. ISBN 978-0-691-05091-1.
  21. ^ Keohane, Robert and Joseph Nye (1989). Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition. Boston: Little, Brown and Company. p. 23. ISBN 9780316489362.
  22. ^ Keohane, Robert and Joseph Nye (1989). Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition. Boston: Little, Brown and Company. pp. 23–24. ISBN 9780316489362.
  23. ^ Waltz, 90; quoted in Richard Ned Lebow, "The long peace, the end of the cold war, and the failure of realism", International Organization, 48, 2 (Spring 1994), 273
  24. ^ Norman Angell, The Great Illusion, (1909) cited from 1933 ed. (New York: G.P. Putnam’s Sons), p. 137.
  25. ^ a b Keohane, Robert and Lisa Martin (Summer 1995). "The Promise of Institutionalist Theory". International Security. 20 (1): 47. doi:10.2307/2539214. JSTOR 2539214. S2CID 29960902.
  26. ^ Robert O. Keohane and Lisa L. Martin, "The Promise of Institutionalist Theory", International Security 20, no. 1 (Summer 1995), 47.
  27. ^ Mearsheimer, John (Summer 1995). "A Realist Reply" (PDF). International Security. 20 (1): 82–83. doi:10.2307/2539218. JSTOR 2539218. S2CID 154731141. Archived (PDF) from the original on 23 December 2018. Retrieved 25 April 2013.
  28. ^ Mearsheimer, 83–87.
  29. ^ a b Mearsheimer, John (Summer 1995). "A Realist Reply" (PDF). International Security. 20 (1): 83. doi:10.2307/2539218. JSTOR 2539218. S2CID 154731141. Archived (PDF) from the original on 23 December 2018. Retrieved 25 April 2013.
  30. ^ Mearsheimer, John (Summer 1995). "A Realist Reply" (PDF). International Security. 20 (1): 87. doi:10.2307/2539218. JSTOR 2539218. S2CID 154731141. Archived (PDF) from the original on 23 December 2018. Retrieved 25 April 2013.
mva是什么单位 停滞是什么意思 转述句是什么意思 超市理货员是做什么的 西米露是什么材料做的
附带是什么意思 卡介苗是预防什么的 行号是什么 微波炉蒸鸡蛋羹几分钟用什么火 什么东西越洗越脏答案
1956年属什么生肖 溶血症是什么意思 ccb是什么药物 胸闷气短吃什么中成药 小孩早上起床咳嗽是什么原因
已故是什么意思 舌苔发白是什么情况 妈妈的手像什么 土耳其烤肉是用什么肉 什么水果对皮肤好
喉咙痛吃什么水果好得最快shenchushe.com 孩子过敏性咳嗽吃什么药好hcv7jop9ns9r.cn 治疗白斑最有效的方法是什么hcv8jop8ns4r.cn 87年属什么的hcv7jop5ns5r.cn 脚趾脱皮是什么原因hcv8jop1ns0r.cn
72年五行属什么sanhestory.com 转诊是什么意思hcv9jop2ns4r.cn 脸一边大一边小是什么原因hcv9jop6ns1r.cn 晖字五行属什么hcv8jop5ns4r.cn 是谁在敲打我窗是什么歌xinjiangjialails.com
打更是什么意思hcv9jop6ns0r.cn 燕窝是什么东西hebeidezhi.com 飞机用什么油hcv7jop9ns1r.cn 北京有什么特产hcv8jop9ns0r.cn 什么负什么名hcv9jop4ns9r.cn
避孕套什么牌子好用又安全hcv8jop6ns1r.cn 吃什么能提高免疫力shenchushe.com 梦见青蛙是什么意思cl108k.com 便秘吃什么可以调理hcv8jop8ns5r.cn 胃息肉吃什么好hcv9jop2ns5r.cn
百度