怀孕乳头会有什么变化| 老是口腔溃疡是什么原因| 端午节有什么活动| 落荒而逃什么意思| 雅五行属性是什么| 角是什么意思| 暧昧是什么意思| 稀料对人体有什么危害| 左肩后背疼是什么原因| 亲热是什么意思| 核磁共振是什么| 猴跟什么生肖相冲| 舌苔黄腻厚是什么原因| 经期提前是什么原因| 咽炎吃什么药好| 黄体囊肿是什么意思| 从头再来什么意思| 人生没有什么不可放下| 喝中药不能吃什么| 小便发黄是什么原因引起的| 犯太岁是什么意思啊| 左眉上方有痣代表什么| et什么意思| 甲子日是什么意思| hpv什么时候检查最好| 成年人改名字需要什么手续| 月经期吃什么好| php是什么语言| 验血糖挂什么科| 胰腺在人体什么位置| 西洋参有什么作用和功效| 一个火一个旦读什么字| 火头鱼是什么鱼| 茄子有什么功效和作用| 额头长痘痘是什么原因怎么调理| 廉洁奉公是什么意思| 阴道发痒是什么原因| 脑供血不足吃什么中药| 线差是什么意思| 背影杀是什么意思| 包涵是什么意思| 不以为然的意思是什么| 腿肿是什么原因引起的| 杨梅吃了有什么好处| 头疼挂什么科室| 什么是半月板损伤| 周星驰为什么不结婚| 八十岁是什么之年| 八九年属什么| 猩红热是什么| 镜花水月是什么意思| 什么叫慢阻肺| 马上是什么意思| 脑血管堵塞是什么症状| 嘴巴发苦吃什么药| 怀字五行属什么| 无春年是什么意思| 厕所里应该摆什么花| 吃什么上火| 红花是什么生肖| 梦见杀蛇是什么意思| 风寒吃什么感冒药| 高锰酸钾加什么会爆炸| 师长是什么军衔| 肝炎吃什么药| 梦见偷桃子是什么意思| ec50是什么意思| 什么是化石| 天伦之乐什么意思| 口吐白沫是什么生肖| 蝉什么时候叫| 嫖娼是什么意思| 血沉是查什么病的| 宝宝乳糖不耐受喝什么奶粉比较好| 骶管小囊肿是什么意思| 头晕恶心想吐吃什么药| 放射治疗是什么意思| 马革裹尸什么意思| 男人时间短吃什么药| 女性潮红是什么意思| 绿豆和什么食物相克| 阿司匹林什么时间吃最好| 补气吃什么食物| 阴道发臭是什么原因| 牛奶不能和什么东西一起吃| 脚有酸味是什么原因| 喝酒会得什么病| 是什么为什么怎么办| 三个水读什么| 无回声结节是什么意思| 乳头长什么样| 哺乳期牙龈肿痛可以吃什么药| 8月8号什么星座| 胸痛挂什么科| 什么是烂桃花| 硒是什么意思| 孕吐最早什么时候开始| 抗氧化什么意思| 土茯苓和什么煲汤最好| 尿葡萄糖高是什么原因| 烤油边是什么| 养殖业什么最赚钱农村| 命中注定是什么意思| 质子泵抑制剂是什么药| 1989年是什么蛇| 梦见生肉是什么征兆| 抓阄什么意思| 体温低是什么原因| 荷叶加什么减肥最快| 用纸盒能做什么手工| 登革热是什么| 狗牯脑茶属于什么茶| 孕妇胃疼吃什么药| 睾丸扭转有什么症状| 吃什么最减肥| 荷花的花语是什么| 检查过敏源挂什么科| 生物医学工程专业学什么| 天是什么结构的字| 青云志是什么意思| 什么是结节| 政治家是什么意思| 脚转筋是什么原因| 坚果是什么| 黑米和什么一起搭配煮粥最佳| 什么叫放射性疼痛| 什么食物含胶原蛋白最多| 听佛歌有什么好处| 冠心病有什么症状| 料理机是干什么用的| 头晕脑胀吃什么药| 圣大保罗属于什么档次| 9月19号什么星座| happy halloween是什么意思| 罗汉果有什么功效和作用| 肺结核钙化是什么意思| 女性尿频尿急吃什么药| 掉头发是什么原因男性| 肝在人体什么位置| 小麦淀粉可以做什么| 东北方五行属什么| 滨海新区有什么好玩的地方| 京剧脸谱黑色代表什么| 舌苔开裂是什么原因呢| 拉大便肛门口疼痛什么原因| 头眩晕吃什么药| 鼻塞喉咙痛吃什么药| 江西有什么特产| 妇科臭氧治疗的作用是什么| 40岁男人学什么乐器好| 王莲是什么植物| 毛豆炒什么好吃| 医院验光挂什么科| 总胆红素高是什么病| 刘邦是什么星座| 千里走单骑是什么意思| 孔子名什么| 吃饭快了有什么坏处| 起诉离婚需要什么材料| 7.2什么星座| 砂仁后下是什么意思| 断眉有什么说法| 胸腔积液吃什么药最有效| 阴性阳性什么意思| 嗓子有点疼吃什么药| 肝结节是什么意思| 什么水果含维生素c最多| 夏至未至是什么意思| 金桔什么时候开花结果| 十月初是什么星座| 晚餐吃什么| 做什么能快速赚钱| 肝血管瘤有什么症状| 手足口疫苗叫什么名字| 白头翁是什么动物| 刻舟求剑是什么生肖| 白化病有什么危害吗| 为什么一直拉肚子| 常州有什么特产| 山东为什么简称鲁| 辣根是什么| 母仪天下是什么意思| 修造是什么意思| 1960年是什么年| 回肠荡气什么意思| 什么是概念车| 心率失常是什么意思| 双签是什么意思| 秋天可以干什么| 叶酸有什么作用和功效| 什么是双规| 聚乙二醇是什么| 喝啤酒头疼是什么原因| 书签是什么| 资治通鉴讲的是什么| 孕妇吃什么| 用凝胶排出豆腐渣一样的东西是什么原因| 主任是什么意思| 乳胶是什么意思| 强心剂是什么意思| 什么叫有氧运动| 中指尖麻木是什么原因| 甲亢吃什么药好得快| 喉咙里老是有痰是什么原因| 梦见冥币是什么意思| pretty是什么意思| 山宗读什么| 什么属相不能挂山水画| 肾气不足是什么原因| 路亚竿什么品牌好| 朋友的意义是什么| 保税仓是什么意思| 梦见自己剪头发是什么意思| 全身酸痛是什么原因| 巴适什么意思| m的意思是什么| 血常规是检查什么的| php是什么语言| 手指关节疼痛挂什么科| 真菌性外耳道炎用什么药| 孕期脸上长痘痘是什么原因| 达人是什么意思| 劫煞是什么意思| 扁桃体1度肿大是什么意思| 老放臭屁是什么原因| 婴幼儿屁股红擦什么| 522是什么意思| 衣原体阳性是什么病| 手指甲上的月牙代表什么| 背疼挂什么科| 鸭嘴鱼吃什么食物| 憔悴是什么意思| 为什么讨厌犹太人| 睡觉为什么会流口水| 蹭饭是什么意思| 什么是婚检| 乳腺增生的前兆是什么| 一个虫一个圣念什么| 人生只剩归途什么意思| 脸麻是什么原因| 早餐吃什么英语怎么说| 炒木耳为什么会炸锅| 减肥吃什么食物瘦得快| 新生儿足底采血检查什么项目| 天方夜谭是什么生肖| 巨蟹女喜欢什么样的男生| 十二生肖分别是什么| 什么是尾货| 夏天适合种什么蔬菜| 月经褐色量少是什么原因| 潮吹是什么感觉| 梦见抓甲鱼是什么意思| 重金属中毒喝什么解毒| 武汉有什么好玩的地方| 外阴炎用什么药| 可定是什么药| 咽喉肿痛吃什么消炎药| 瓜子脸适合什么刘海| 纯色是什么意思| 亚撒西是什么意思| 右眼皮一直跳什么预兆| 消化不良用什么药| 碟鱼头是什么鱼| 沙拉酱可以做什么美食| 百度Jump to content

攻克高难险整治牛皮癣 杆石桥二期违法户外广告全拆除

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Collective action refers to action taken together by a group of people whose goal is to enhance their condition and achieve a common objective.[1] It is a term that has formulations and theories in many areas of the social sciences including psychology, sociology, anthropology, political science and economics.

The social identity model

[edit]

Researchers Martijn van Zomeren, Tom Postmes, and Russell Spears conducted a meta-analysis of over 180 studies of collective action, in an attempt to integrate three dominant socio-psychological perspectives explaining antecedent conditions to this phenomenon – injustice, efficacy, and identity.[2] In their resultant 2008 review article, an integrative Social Identity Model of Collective Action (SIMCA) was proposed which accounts for interrelationships among the three predictors as well as their predictive capacities for collective action.[2] An important assumption of this approach is that people tend to respond to subjective states of disadvantage, which may or may not flow from objective physical and social reality.

Perceived injustice

[edit]

Examining collective action through perceived injustice was initially guided by relative deprivation theory (RDT). RDT focuses on a subjective state of unjust disadvantage, proposing that engaging in fraternal (group-based) social comparisons with others may result in feelings of relative deprivation that foster collective action. Group-based emotions resulting from perceived injustice, such as anger, are thought to motivate collective action in an attempt to rectify the state of unfair deprivation.[2] The extent to which individuals respond to this deprivation involves several different factors and varies from extremely high to extremely low across different settings.[3] Meta-analysis results confirm that effects of injustice causally predict collective action, highlighting the theoretical importance of this variable.[2]

Perceived efficacy

[edit]

Moving beyond RDT, scholars suggested that in addition to a sense of injustice, people must also have the objective, structural resources necessary to mobilize change through social protest. An important psychological development saw this research instead directed towards subjective expectations and beliefs that unified effort (collective action) is a viable option for achieving group-based goals – this is referred to as perceived collective efficacy. Empirically, collective efficacy is shown to causally affect collective action among a number of populations across varied contexts.[2]

Social identity

[edit]

Social identity theory (SIT) suggests that people strive to achieve and maintain positive social identities associated with their group memberships.[4] Where a group membership is disadvantaged (for example, low status), SIT implicates three variables in the evocation of collective action to improve conditions for the group – permeability of group boundaries,[5] legitimacy of the intergroup structures, and the stability of these relationships. For example, when disadvantaged groups perceive intergroup status relationships as illegitimate and unstable, collective action is predicted to occur, in an attempt to change status structures for the betterment of the disadvantaged group.

Meta-analysis results also confirm that social identity causally predicts collective action across a number of diverse contexts. Additionally, the integrated SIMCA affords another important role to social identity – that of a psychological bridge forming the collective base from which both collective efficacy and group injustice may be conceived.[citation needed]

Model refinement

[edit]

While there is sound empirical support for the causal importance of SIMCA's key theoretical variables on collective action,[2] more recent literature has addressed the issue of reverse causation, finding support for a related, yet distinct, encapsulation model of social identity in collective action (EMSICA).[6] This model suggests that perceived group efficacy and perceived injustice provide the basis from which social identity emerges, highlighting an alternative causal pathway to collective action. Recent research has sought to integrate SIMCA with intergroup contact theory (see Cakal, Hewstone, Schw?r, & Heath[7]) and others have extended SIMCA through bridging morality research with the collective action literature (see van Zomeren, Postmes, & Spears[8] for a review).

Also, utopian thinking has been proposed as an antecendant to collective action, aside to the route affecting perceived injustice, efficacy, or social identity.[9] Utopian thinking contributes to accessing cognitive alternatives, which are imagined models of societies that are different from the current society.[9] Cognitive alternatives are proposed by many social identity theorists as an effective way to increase collective action.[10][11] Moreover, utopian thinking has the potential to increase perceived injustice, perceived efficacy, or form new social identities and therefore affect collective action.[9]

Public good

[edit]

The economic theory of collective action is concerned with the provision of public goods (and other collective consumption) through the collaboration of two or more individuals, and the impact of externalities on group behavior. It is more commonly referred to as Public Choice. Mancur Olson's 1965 book The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, is an important early analysis of the problems of public good cost.

Besides economics, the theory has found many applications in political science, sociology, communication, anthropology and environmentalism.

Collective action problem

[edit]

The term collective action problem describes the situation in which multiple individuals would all benefit from a certain action, but has an associated cost making it implausible that any individual can or will undertake and solve it alone. The ideal solution is then to undertake this as a collective action, the cost of which is shared. Situations like this include the prisoner's dilemma, a collective action problem in which no communication is allowed, the free rider problem, and the tragedy of the commons, also known as the problem with open access.[12] An allegorical metaphor often used to describe the problem is "belling the cat".[13]

Solutions to collective action problems include mutually binding agreements, government regulation, privatisation, and assurance contracts, also known as crowdacting.[14]

Exploitation of the great by the small

[edit]

Mancur Olson made the claim that individual rational choice leads to situations where individuals with more resources will carry a higher burden in the provision of the public good than poorer ones.[15] Poorer individuals will usually have little choice but to opt for the free rider strategy, i.e., they will attempt to benefit from the public good without contributing to its provision. This may also encourage the under-production (inefficient production) of the public good.

Institutional design

[edit]

While public goods are often provided by governments, this is not always the case. Various institutional designs have been studied with the aim of reducing the collaborative failure. The best design for a given situation depends on the production costs, the utility function, and the collaborative effects, amongst other things. Here are only some examples:

Joint products

[edit]

A joint-product model analyzes the collaborative effect of joining a private good to a public good. For example, a tax deduction (private good) can be tied to a donation to a charity (public good).

It can be shown that the provision of the public good increases when tied to the private good, as long as the private good is provided by a monopoly (otherwise the private good would be provided by competitors without the link to the public good).

Clubs

[edit]

Some institutional design, e.g., intellectual property rights, can introduce an exclusion mechanism and turn a pure public good into an impure public good artificially.

If the costs of the exclusion mechanism are not higher than the gain from the collaboration, clubs can emerge. James M. Buchanan showed in his seminal paper that clubs can be an efficient alternative to government interventions.[16]

A nation can be seen as a club whose members are its citizens. Government would then be the manager of this club.

Federated structure

[edit]

In some cases, theory shows that collaboration emerges spontaneously in smaller groups rather than in large ones (see e.g. Dunbar's number). This explains why labor unions or charities often have a federated structure.

In philosophy

[edit]

Since the late 20th century, analytic philosophers have been exploring the nature of collective action in the sense of acting together, as when people paint a house together, go for a walk together, or together execute a pass play. These particular examples have been central for three of the philosophers who have made well known contributions to this literature: Michael Bratman, Margaret Gilbert, and John Searle, respectively.

In (Gilbert 1989) and subsequent articles and book chapters including Gilbert (2006, chapter 7), whom argues for an account of collective action according to which this rests on a special kind of interpersonal commitment, what Gilbert calls a "joint commitment". A joint commitment in Gilbert's sense is not a matter of a set of personal commitments independently created by each of the participants, as when each makes a personal decision to do something. Rather, it is a single commitment to whose creation each participant makes a contribution. Thus suppose that one person says "Shall we go for a walk?" and the other says "Yes, let's". Gilbert proposes that as a result of this exchange the parties are jointly committed to go for a walk, and thereby obligated to one another to act as if they were parts of a single person taking a walk. Joint commitments can be created less explicitly and through processes that are more extended in time. One merit of a joint commitment account of collective action, in Gilbert's view, is that it explains the fact that those who are out on a walk together, for instance, understand that each of them is in a position to demand corrective action of the other if he or she acts in ways that affect negatively the completion of their walk. In (Gilbert 2006a) she discusses the pertinence of joint commitment to collective actions in the sense of the theory of rational choice.

In Searle (1990) Searle argues that what lies at the heart of a collective action is the presence in the mind of each participant of a "we-intention". Searle does not give an account of we-intentions or, as he also puts it, "collective intentionality", but insists that they are distinct from the "I-intentions" that animate the actions of persons acting alone.

In Bratman (1993) Bratman proposed that, roughly, two people "share an intention" to paint a house together when each intends that the house is painted by virtue of the activity of each, and also intends that it is so painted by virtue of the intention of each that it is so painted. That these conditions obtain must also be "common knowledge" between the participants.

Discussion in this area continues to expand, and has influenced discussions in other disciplines including anthropology, developmental psychology, and economics. One general question is whether it is necessary to think in terms that go beyond the personal intentions of individual human beings properly to characterize what it is to act together. Bratman's account does not go beyond such personal intentions. Gilbert's account, with its invocation of joint commitment, does go beyond them. Searle's account does also, with its invocation of collective intentionality. The question of whether and how one must account for the existence of mutual obligations when there is a collective intention is another of the issues in this area of inquiry.

Spontaneous consensus

[edit]

In addition to the psychological mechanisms of collective action as explained by the social identity model, researchers have developed sociological models of why collective action exists and have studied under what conditions collective action emerges.[17] Along this social dimension, a special case of the general collective action problem is one of collective agreement: how does a group of agents (humans, animals, robots, etc.) reach consensus about a decision or belief, in the absence of central organization? Common examples can be found from domains as diverse as biology (flocking, shoaling and schooling, and general collective animal behavior), economics (stock market bubbles), and sociology (social conventions and norms) among others.

Consensus is distinct from the collective action problem in that there often is not an explicit goal, benefit, or cost of action but rather it concerns itself with a social equilibrium of the individuals involved (and their beliefs). And it can be considered spontaneous when it emerges without the presence of a centralized institution among self-interested individuals.[18]

Dimensions

[edit]

Spontaneous consensus can be considered along 4 dimensions involving the social structure of the individuals participating (local versus global) in the consensus as well as the processes (competitive vs cooperative) involved in reaching consensus:[17]

  • Competitive
  • Cooperative
  • Local
  • Global

Competitive versus cooperative

[edit]

The underlying processes of spontaneous consensus can be viewed either as cooperation among individuals trying to coordinate themselves through their interactions or as competition between the alternatives or choices to be decided upon.[17] Depending on the dynamics of the individuals involved as well as the context of the alternatives considered for consensus, the process can be wholly cooperative, wholly competitive, or a mix of the two.

Local versus global

[edit]

The distinction between local and global consensus can be viewed in terms of the social structure underlying the network of individuals participating in the consensus making process. Local consensus occurs when there is agreement between groups of neighboring nodes while global consensus refers to the state in which most of the population has reached an agreement.[17] How and why consensus is reached is dependent on both the structure of the social network of individuals as well as the presence (or lack) of centralized institutions.

Equilibrium mechanisms

[edit]

There are many mechanisms (social and psychological) that have been identified to underlie the consensus making process.[17] They have been used to both explain the emergence of spontaneous consensus and understand how to facilitate an equilibrium between individuals and can be grouped according to their role in the process.

  • Facilitation of Equilibrium
  • Selection of Alternatives
    • Logical Reflection[23]
    • Psychological and shared biases[21]
    • Chance (when all alternatives are equivalent)[24]

Methods and techniques

[edit]

Due to the interdisciplinary nature of both the mechanisms as well as the applications of spontaneous consensus, a variety of techniques have been developed to study the emergence and evolution of spontaneous cooperation. Two of the most widely used are game theory and social network analysis.

Game theory

[edit]

Traditionally game theory has been used to study zero-sum games but has been extended to many different types of games. Relevant to the study of spontaneous consensus are cooperative and non-cooperative games. Since a consensus must be reached without the presence of any external authoritative institution for it to be considered spontaneous, non-cooperative games and Nash equilibrium have been the dominant paradigm for which to study its emergence.

In the context of non-cooperative games, a consensus is a formal Nash equilibrium that all players tend towards through self-enforcing alliances or agreements.

An important case study of the underlying mathematical dynamics is the coordination game. Even when coordination is desired, it can be difficult to achieve due to incomplete information and constrained time horizons.

Social network analysis

[edit]

An alternative approach to studying the emergence of spontaneous consensus—that avoids many of the unnatural or overly constrained assumptions of game theoretic models—is the use of network based methods and social network analysis (SNA). These SNA models are theoretically grounded in the communication mechanism[19] of facilitating consensus and describe its emergence through the information propagation processes of the network (behavioral contagion). Through the spread of influence (and ideas) between agents participating in the consensus, local and global consensus can emerge if the agents in the network achieve a shared equilibrium state. Leveraging this model of consensus, researchers have shown that local peer influence can be used to reach a global consensus and cooperation across the entire network.[25] While this model of consensus and cooperation has been shown to be successful in certain contexts, research suggest that communication and social influence cannot be fully captured by simple contagion models[26] and as such a pure contagion based model of consensus may have limits.

See also

[edit]

Footnotes

[edit]
  1. ^ "collective action problem - collective action". Encyclop?dia Britannica.
  2. ^ a b c d e f van Zomeren, M.; Postmes, T.; Spears, R. (2008). "Toward an integrative social identity model of collective action: A quantitative research synthesis of three socio-psychological perspectives". Psychological Bulletin. 134 (4): 504–535. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.576.5638. doi:10.1037/0033-2909.134.4.504. PMID 18605818. S2CID 18741272.
  3. ^ Ostrom, Elinor (2000). "Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms" (PDF). The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 14 (3): 137–158. doi:10.1257/jep.14.3.137. hdl:10535/5683.
  4. ^ Tajfel, H.; Turner, J.C. (1979). "An integrative theory of inter-group conflict. In W.G. Austin & S. Worchel (Eds.)". The Social Psychology of Inter-group Relations: 33–47.
  5. ^ Stephen C. Wright; Donald M. Taylor; Fathali M. Moghaddam (June 1990). "Responding to Membership in a Disadvantaged Group: From Acceptance to Collective Protest". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 58 (6): 994–1003. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.58.6.994.
  6. ^ Thomas, E.F.; Mavor, K.I.; McGarty, C. (2011). "Social identities facilitate and encapsulate action-relevant constructs: A test of the social identity model of collective action". Group Processes and Intergroup Relations. 15 (1): 75–88. doi:10.1177/1368430211413619. hdl:1885/66105. S2CID 53577195.
  7. ^ Cakal, H.; Hewstone, M.; Schw?r, G.; Heath, A. (2011). "An investigation of the social identity model of collective action and the 'sedative' effect of intergroup contact among Black and White students in South Africa". British Journal of Social Psychology. 50 (4): 606–627. doi:10.1111/j.2044-8309.2011.02075.x. PMID 22122025.
  8. ^ van Zomeren, M.; Postmes, T.; Spears, R. (2012). "On conviction's collective consequences: Integrating moral conviction with the social identity model of collective action" (PDF). British Journal of Social Psychology. 51 (1): 52–71. doi:10.1111/j.2044-8309.2010.02000.x. PMID 22435846. S2CID 44659756.
  9. ^ a b c Fernando, Julian W.; O'Brien, Léan V.; Burden, Nicholas J.; Judge, Madeline; Kashima, Yoshihisa (March 2020). "Greens or space invaders: Prominent utopian themes and effects on social change motivation". European Journal of Social Psychology. 50 (2): 278–291. doi:10.1002/ejsp.2607. hdl:10536/DRO/DU:30136822. ISSN 0046-2772.
  10. ^ Tajfel, Henri; Turner, John C. (2025-08-06). The Social Identity Theory of Intergroup Behavior. Psychology Press. pp. 276–293. ISBN 978-0-203-50598-4.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  11. ^ Reicher, S. D., & Haslam, S. A. (2012). Change we can believe in: The role of social identity, cognitive alternatives, and leadership in group mobilization and social transformation. In B. Wagoner, E. Jensen, & J. A. Oldmeadow (Eds.), Culture and social change: Transforming society through the power of ideas. IAP Information Age Publishing. pp. 53–73.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  12. ^ Archived at Ghostarchive and the Wayback Machine: Agar, Jesse (9 June 2015). "Tragedy of the Commons │ The Problem with Open Access". Youtube. This Place (youtube channel). Retrieved Jun 9, 2015.
  13. ^ Dowding, Keith (1996). Power. University of Minnesota Press. pp. 31 ff. ISBN 978-0-8166-2941-1.
  14. ^ Archived at Ghostarchive and the Wayback Machine: van den Akker, Ron (7 September 2016). "Crowdacting". YouTube. Bord&Stift. Retrieved Sep 7, 2016.
  15. ^ Olson, Mancur (1965). "logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups" (Document). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  16. ^ Buchanan, James M. (1965). "An Economic Theory of Clubs". Economica. 32 (125): 1–14. doi:10.2307/2552442. JSTOR 2552442.
  17. ^ a b c d e Baronchelli, Andrea (2018). "The Emergence of Consensus". Royal Society Open Science. 5 (2): 172189. arXiv:1704.07767. Bibcode:2018RSOS....572189B. doi:10.1098/rsos.172189. PMC 5830794. PMID 29515905.
  18. ^ Sugden, Robert (1989). "Spontaneous order". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3 (4): 85–97. doi:10.1257/jep.3.4.85.
  19. ^ a b Garrod, Simon; Doherty, Gwyneth (1994). "Conversation, co-ordination and convention: An empirical investigation of how groups establish linguistic conventions". Cognition. 53 (3): 181–215. doi:10.1016/0010-0277(94)90048-5. PMID 7842633. S2CID 26766644.
  20. ^ Boyd, Robert; Richerson, Peter (1992). "Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups". Ethology and Sociobiology. 13 (3): 171–195. doi:10.1016/0162-3095(92)90032-Y.
  21. ^ a b Schelling, Thomas (1960). The strategy of conflict. Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674840317. {{cite book}}: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help)
  22. ^ Asch, Solomon (1955). "Opinions and social pressure". In Aronson, Elliot (ed.). Readings about the social animal. Macmillan. pp. 17–26. ISBN 9780716759669. {{cite book}}: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help)
  23. ^ Harsanyi, John; Selten, Reinhard (1988). A general theory of equilibrium selection in games. MIT Press Books. p. 1. ISBN 9780262582384.
  24. ^ Young, H Peyton (1996). "The economics of convention". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 10 (2): 105–122. doi:10.1257/jep.10.2.105. JSTOR 2138484. S2CID 155064244.
  25. ^ Mani, Ankur; Rahwan, Iyad; Pentland, Alex (2013). "Inducing Peer Pressure to Promote Cooperation". Scientific Reports. 3 (1735): 1735. Bibcode:2013NatSR...3.1735M. doi:10.1038/srep01735. PMC 3636514. PMID 23619166.
  26. ^ Alshamsi, Aamena; Pianesi, Fabio; Lepri, Bruno; Pentland, Alex; Rahwan, Iyad (2015). "Beyond Contagion: Reality Mining Reveals Complex Patterns of Social Influence". PLOS ONE. 10 (8): e0135740. arXiv:1507.04192. Bibcode:2015PLoSO..1035740A. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0135740. PMC 4551670. PMID 26313449.

Bibliography

[edit]
[edit]
梅毒是什么 间歇性是什么意思 内瘘是什么意思 大腿根部痒用什么药膏 立春是什么时候
什么水果是热性的 多囊肾是什么病 刻薄什么意思 吃什么降血压 prp是什么意思
肝囊肿是什么病 苦瓜泡水喝有什么功效 窦性心律不齐是什么 金达克宁和达克宁有什么区别 血压低吃什么补
绍兴本地人喝什么黄酒 o型血为什么招蚊子 什么是无产阶级 忻字五行属什么 什么动物三只爪
鼻窦炎是什么病hcv8jop5ns3r.cn 今天是什么月hcv8jop0ns4r.cn 自尊是什么意思xjhesheng.com 怀孕做糖耐是检查什么bfb118.com 7月14日什么星座clwhiglsz.com
conch是什么牌子hcv8jop6ns8r.cn 生精补精吃什么药最快hcv9jop7ns9r.cn 指甲变空是什么原因qingzhougame.com 脚背发麻是什么原因引起的hcv8jop0ns7r.cn 头孢吃多了有什么副作用hcv8jop9ns8r.cn
稀料对人体有什么危害hcv9jop0ns1r.cn mild是什么意思hcv8jop4ns9r.cn 摩西摩西是什么意思hcv8jop3ns6r.cn 什么人喜欢天天下雨hcv8jop2ns2r.cn 吃银耳有什么功效和作用naasee.com
抗核抗体弱阳性说明什么hcv8jop4ns1r.cn 心跳不规律是什么原因hcv8jop6ns3r.cn 42天产后复查都查什么hcv8jop8ns1r.cn 维生素e的功效与作用是什么hcv8jop9ns9r.cn 血脂稠吃什么食物好hcv7jop7ns2r.cn
百度